Tuesday, September 18, 2012

Selgin and Measures of Spending

George Selgin is worried that QE3 will lead to an unsustainable boom.   He is concerned that the Fed is repeating the mistake it made in 2002.   Sumner responded with skepticism that monetary policy was too expansionary during that period.   Sumner's view is "maybe a little."

Sumner wrote:

1. NGDP grew at a slower rate during the 2001-07 expansion than during any other expansion during my lifetime.
2. NGDP growth modestly exceeded 5% during the peak of the housing boom.


Selgin came back suggesting that NGDP is the wrong measure of  spending on output.   He suggests that Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers is better measure of spending on output.   He correctly points out that Niskanen favored that measure.   Further, Market Monetarists are well aware that our "fellow travelers" among the "free bankers," have favored that measure.

Selgin reproduces a diagram from Niskanen showing the deviation of final demand from trend. 


While the diagram uses Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers, much the same diagram can be shown using nominal GDP.   This diagram shows the deviation of spending on output from trend.   This is a diagram that is based upon a level target.    There was a large positive deviation during the Dot.Com boom.   From the point of view of a growth path target for nominal GDP, monetary policy was too expansionary during the Dot.Com boom.

However, the question at hand is not the Dot.Com boom, but rather the housing boom.    Niskanen's diagram ends with a closing gap from trend.   What happened?   Was the run up in housing prices and increase in housing construction due to an excessively expansionary monetary policy?   Was spending on output above trend during in 2002 to 2005?

Selgin provides charts showing the growth rates of nominal GDP and Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers.





While Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers was growing more quickly than nominal GPD  from 2004 to 2007, that is hardly unusual.   Both show spending on output growing more quickly than the long term trend of 5.5 percent.

The problem with Selgin's analysis of the chart is that it assumes growth rate targeting.   From 2001 to 2003 both measures of spending grew below trend.   The result was that both fell below the trend growth path.   To return to that growth path, both needed to grow faster than trend.    Pretty much all of the more than 5 percent growth in both measures of spending between 2004 and 2007 was a return of spending to the trend growth path.

Here are the levels of the two series:



Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers is greater than Nominal GDP and gap looks to be increasing after 1998. How do they compare to trend?   Here is nominal GDP.




And here is Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers:



Both show the Dot.Com boom and that spending fell below trend in the 2001 recession.  It is true that Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers shows the a slight upward deviation starting in 2005, but it is pretty insignificant.

What is the difference between nominal GDP and Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers?    The major difference is the trade deficit.   Nominal GDP for the U.S. measures total spending on goods and services produced in the U.S.    Consumer goods and services, capital goods and government goods and services produced in the U.S. and sold to people in the U.S. are included, as are consumer goods and services and capital goods sold to foreigners.    Imports aren't included.    Spending on foreign goods and services aren't included.

Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers includes imports.  It includes spending by U.S. residents (firms and households and government) on foreign goods and services.    It does not include exports, spending by foreigners on goods and services produced in the U.S.

The gap between the two is the trade deficit.   The growing gap is the growing trade deficit.   The difference between their growth rates is the growth rate of the trade deficit.

Selgin approvingly cites Niskanen, who argued that spending by Americans is more closely related to an excess supply of money for Americans than is spending on American products.    And so, he argued, Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers is the more appropriate target for monetary policy.

While Niskanen is probably correct that an excess supply of money by Americans impacts spending by Americans,  a monetary authority that creates money that is held by both foreigners as well as its "own" citizens would need to be concerned about a possible excess supply of money in the hands of foreigners.   U.S. exports are a natural way for foreigners to spend excess U.S. dollars.

Further, not only is it unlikely that only imports would be impacted by an excess supply of money, there is a rather direct connection between "excess" imports and spending on domestic output.    Those foreigners selling the products now have the "excess dollars" which they would naturally sell for their own currency.   The resulting depreciation in the exchange rate makes exports cheaper for foreigners and imported goods more expensive.   That makes import competing goods look like bargains.   And so, through the depreciation of the exchange rate, an excess supply of money spent on imported goods rapidly translates into demand for domestic product--exports and import competing goods.   The ability of speculators to buy foreign currency can speed up the process.

More importantly, while a growing trade deficit could be the consequence of an excess supply of money, there are many other possible reasons for a growing trade deficit.   In particular, growing foreign investment will result in a growing trade deficit and so a growing gap between nominal GDP and Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers.   German auto companies buying German machinery for their new plants in South Carolina, for example.

But then, German car companies and their employees could take the money they earned from exports to the U.S. and put it in their German banks, and the German banks could purchase U.S. asset backed commercial paper, that is backed by mortgage backed securities, and the mortgages could be used to pay for over-priced houses in Las Vegas.   Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers would expand relative to nominal GDP.   And problems just might develop.   But it would not be because of an excess supply of money.

Suppose Chinese toy manufacturers retain earnings and hold them in Chinese state banks.   The Chinese state banks accumulate funds in the Bank of China, which in turn accumulates U.S. T-bills.   This occurs at such a rate that T-bill yields become very low.   Investors in U.S. money markets look for a better yield and buy asset backed commercial paper.   The assets backing the commercial paper are mortgage backed securities.   They are used to fund mortgages to pay for over priced houses in Las Vegas.   Again, Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers expand relative to Nominal GDP.   Problems might develop.   But it isn't because of an excess supply of money.

The other difference between nominal GDP and Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers is inventory investment. Final Sales does not include the accumulation of inventories.  Final Sales of Domestic Product is nominal GDP without the inventories--it includes exports and not imports.  

There is a sound intuition for leaving off inventories.   If spending on output grows "too fast" or "too slow" relative to productive capacity, then inventories will be depleted or accumulate.   In principles of economics this is called "unplanned inventory investment."    Avoiding "unplanned inventory investment" seems like a good idea, and so stabilizing final sales seems like a good idea.

However, the only way that any of these statistics account for "intermediate goods," is through changes in inventories.   Rather than focusing on inventories of cars, think about inventories of car parts, either in the hands of the part manufacturers or the auto companies.   Consider various "raw commodities," like copper or wheat.   These aren't final products but are intermediate goods.   They are only directly counted as inventories in the production process.

For example, if an excess supply of money leads to higher copper prices, then copper inventories will be worth more.   This raises nominal GDP, but it doesn't raise any of the Final Sales measures.

Finally, avoiding unplanned inventory investment is a good thing, but readjusting inventories at any time, including after there has been unplanned inventory investment, is a type of expenditure that requires resources.    A nominal GDP target takes that demand into account.

Nominal GDP is not perfect, but it is better than Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers or Final Sales of Domestic Product.   In my opinion, as much as we honor Bill Niskanen as a pioneer, Market Monetarists have made some progress on these issues.

Even so, I share Selgin's concerns about promising to hold short term interest rates at a near zero rate for an extended period of time.   Similarly, I don't at all like it when the Fed purchases various longer term to maturity assets explaining that their goal is to lower long term interest rates.    Further, that the Fed generally kept nominal GDP close to a trend growth path in the Great Moderation, doesn't necessarily mean that the performance of interest rates or the quantity of money were the same as they would have been if the Fed had clearly articulated that goal.     Leaving aside the desirability of keeping nominal GDP on trend during the Dot-com boom, after nominal GDP fell below that trend, a clear commitment to return nominal GDP to trend could not only have resulted in a more rapid recovery in spending and output, but also resulted in a decrease in short term interest rates that was smaller and of shorter duration.  In other words, inflation targeting using an interest rate instrutment is a really bad idea.

 

7 comments:

  1. Thanks for your thoughtful response, Bill. To reply: you say that 2004-7 was just "making up" for 2000-2003; but may one not claim with equal justice that 2000-2003 was itself "making up" for 1998-2000? In that case, 2004-2007 becomes, once again, a period of excessive spending growth.

    That is to say, turning to your level plots, that I have grave doubts concerning the assumption that the 2007 peak-boom level of spending should itself be regarded as consistent with a healthy trend rather than considerably above it.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. George
      1998-2000 was a mistake, with the Fed letting NGDP rise above trend. Then it undershot in 2001-03, after which it managed to bring NGDP back to trend without overshooting.
      And Bernanke "messed it up".

      Delete
  2. insightful and impressive post.
    Nevertheless, right now I would argue in favor of overshooting on the stimulus side. People need jobs, small businesses need income and profits.

    Secondly, I think the USA has been inoculated against inflation in the last 40 years. International trade, the death of unions, the rise of competitive retail markets. The 1970s inflation was an unusual situation of cost-push inflation marrying an expansive money supply. Even then we did not get hyperinflation, just double digit inflation.

    I don't know of any business today that thinks it has been pricing leverage. Unit labor costs have been flat to down for years.

    The phobia about inflation is mysterious.

    ReplyDelete
  3. "Nominal GDP is not perfect, but it is better than Final Sales to Domestic Purchasers or Final Sales of Domestic Product. In my opinion, as much as we honor Bill Niskanen as a pioneer, Market Monetarists have made some progress on these issues".
    I agree
    http://thefaintofheart.wordpress.com/2012/09/18/50-years-of-us-growth-and-inflation-history-from-a-market-monetarist-perspective/

    ReplyDelete
  4. Why should we be slavish to the 5% trend? Isn't it possible that they've done a reasonable job moving spending back to a trend that is excessive and produces easy money, especially during periods of productivity growth?

    What about Less Than Zero? If it's just about "sticky wages", than why not adjust to a path like 2 or 3% growth so that we don't get productivity norm deflation? And given where we're at now, many years beyond the fall in spending, is now perhaps a GOOD time to adjust to a new path and announce that new path so that new labor agreements can be modified (I guess for teachers unions, because I don't know who else operates with such contracts outside of detroit)? Are there really a significant number of people being kept out of work by labor agreements still in force today from over 5 years ago causing those still employed to snag more income at the expense of the unemployed?

    It's hard for me to believe, on its face, that we should target a trend simply because it is a trend, especially when there's been waves of booms and busts during this lovely trend.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. If you look back at past posts, you will find that I advocate a "Reagan-Volcker" recovery in spending on output, and then a 3 percent target growth path for spending on output going out into the future. I see this as creating a new Great Moderation, but one with price stability.

      It is simply wrong that a more rapid trend growth in spending on output requires loose money and is responsible for booms and busts.

      But shifting between growth paths is disruptive and should be avoided.

      Trying to offset shifts in inflation caused by shifts in productivity are disruptive. Selgin was right about that. On the other hand, the notion that the only trend for nominal GDP growth that avoids disruption is one that generates deflation equal to productivity growth is mistaken.

      Delete
  5. Frankly speaking, these are the concern that almost everyone has; we just need to be careful that we don’t do anything silly. I work with OctaFX broker and with them, I get excellent bonus which is up to 50% on deposit, this is also use able making it even better and that’s why I can be relaxed even with the toughest and probably the most challenging situations. Also, we can get great analysis and news updates daily from them for free.

    ReplyDelete